home *** CD-ROM | disk | FTP | other *** search
- $Unique_ID{how02110}
- $Pretitle{}
- $Title{History Of Monetary Systems
- Part I}
- $Subtitle{}
- $Author{Del Mar, Alexander}
- $Affiliation{}
- $Subject{gold
- coins
- coinage
- roman
- footnote
- money
- empire
- silver
- sacred
- coin
- see
- tables
- }
- $Date{}
- $Log{See Table 27*0211001.tab
- }
- Title: History Of Monetary Systems
- Book: Chapter II: The Sacred Character Of Gold
- Author: Del Mar, Alexander
-
- Part I
-
- Chapter Contents
-
- Coinage the surest mark of sovereignty - Abstention of the Christian
- princes from minting and coining gold, from Pepin to Frederick II. - Dates of
- the earliest Christian coinages of gold in the West - Inadequate reasons
- hitherto given to explain this singular circumstance - Opinions of Camden -
- Ruding - Father Joubert - The true reason given by Procopius - The coinage of
- gold was a Sacred Myth and a prerogative of the Roman emperor - Its origin and
- history - Braminical Code - The Myth during the Roman Republic - During the
- Civil Wars - Conquest of Egypt by Julius Caesar - Seizure of the Oriental
- trade - The Sacred Myth embodied in the Julian Constitution - Popularity and
- longevity of the Myth - It was transmitted by the pagan to the Christian
- Church of Rome, and adopted by the latter - Its importance in throwing light
- upon the relations of the Western kingdoms to the Roman Empire.
-
- The Sacred Character Of Gold
-
- The right to coin money has always been and still remains the surest mark
- and announcement of sovereignty. A curious proof of this is afforded by the
- story told by Edward Thomas, in his "Pathan Kings of Delhi," of that Persian
- commander who, being suspected of a treasonable design towards his sovereign,
- diverted suspicion from himself to the king's son by coining and circulating
- pieces of money with the latter's superscription. ^1 Says Mr. Thomas: "Some,
- perhaps many, of the Mahometan coinages of India constituted merely a sort of
- numismatic proclamation or assertion and declaration of conquest and
- supremacy." In ancient times such conquest and supremacy often embraced the
- triumph of an alien religion. Where printing was uncommon and the newspaper
- unknown, a new gold or silver coinage was the most effective means of
- proclaiming the accession of a new ruler or the era of a new religion. ^1 At
- the period of the earliest voyages of the Portuguese to India, the same
- significance was attached to the prerogative of coinage. Says Duarte Barbosa:
- "There are many other lords in Malabar who wish to call themselves kings, but
- they are not so, because they are not able to coin money. . . . The king of
- Cochin could not coin money, nor roof his house with tiles, under pain of
- losing his fief (to the king of Calicut, his suzerain); but since the
- Portuguese went there, he has been released from this, so that now he lords it
- absolutely and coins money." Father Du Halde, in his "History of China," makes
- a similar statement in reference to that country. Says he: "There were
- formerly twenty-two several places where money was fabricated, at which time
- there were princes so powerful that they were not contented with the rank of
- duke, but assumed the dignity of sovereigns; yet they never durst attempt to
- fabricate money, for, however weak the emperor's authority was, the coins have
- always had the stamp that he commanded." ^2
-
- [Footnote 1: "History Money," p. 89.]
-
- [Footnote 1: Gibbon declared that were all other records destroyed the travels
- of the Emperor Hadrian could be shown from his coins alone. The Emperor
- Theodoric the Goth stamped his coins with the view to instruct posterity
- ("History Money," p. 89, n.)]
-
- [Footnote 2: Duarte Barbosa, pp. 103 and 157; Du Halde, ii., 293.]
-
- The custom of employing coins as a means of promulgating religious
- doctrine and official information was adopted by the Romans during the
- Commonwealth. It may be traced, at a later period, in the otherwise
- superfluous coinages of the Empire. Julius, Hadrian and Theodoric depicted
- the principal events of their reigns upon their coins. In the absence of
- felted paper and printing ink, it was the only means the ancients had of
- printing and disseminating the most important intelligence and opinions.
- Addison correctly regarded the Roman coinage as a sort of "State Gazette," in
- which all the great events of the Empire were periodically published. It had
- this advantage over any other kind of monument: it could not be successfully
- mutilated, forged, or suppressed. Especially is the fabrication and issuance
- of full legal-tender coins the mark of sovereignty. Towards the end of the
- Republic and during the Empire this attribute belonged alone to gold coins;
- therefore, to speak of these is to speak of full legal-tender money. Vassal
- princes, nobles and prelates, under the warrant of their suzerains, everywhere
- struck coins of silver, which, although legal tender in their own domains,
- were not so elsewhere, unless by special warrant from the Basileus; but no
- Christian vassal ever struck gold without intending to proclaim his own
- independent sovereignty and without being prepared to defy the suzerainty of
- the Caesars.
-
- Lenormant, in his great work on the "Moneys of Antiquity," holds similar
- language. "With the exception of the Sassanian coinages down to the reign of
- Sapor III., it is certain that the coinage of gold, no matter where, was
- always intended as a marked defiance to the pretensions of sovereignty by the
- Roman Empire; for example, during the period of the Republic, about B. C. 86,
- the gold coinages of Mithridates, in various places over which he had extended
- his conquests. The supremacy of Rome was so widely accepted both East and
- West, that for many centuries neither the provinces subject directly or
- indirectly to the Basileus, nor even the more or less independent States
- adjacent to the Empire, ever attempted to coin gold money. When gold was
- struck by such States it was as a local money of the Roman sovereign." ^1 As
- such it yielded him seigniorage; it bore his stamp; its use implied and
- acknowledged his suzerainty, both spiritual and temporal; while its issuance
- was subject to such regulations as he chose to impose.
-
- [Footnote 1: Lenormant, ii., 427.]
-
- Commodus refused to believe that his favorite Perennius aspired to the
- Empire until he was shown some pieces of provincial money, upon which appeared
- the effigy of his faithless minister. ^1 Elagabalus condemned Valerius Paetus
- to death for striking some bijoux pieces of gold for his mistress, upon which
- he had imprudently caused his own image to be stamped. ^2 The very first act
- of a Roman sovereign after his accession, election, or proclamation by the
- legions, was to strike coins, that act being deemed the surest mark of
- sovereignty. Vespasian, when proclaimed by the legions in Asia, hurried to
- strike gold and silver coins at Antioch. ^3 Antoninus Diadumenus, the son of
- Macrinus, was no sooner nominated by the legions as the associate of his
- father in the Empire, than the latter hastened to strike money at Antioch in
- his son's name, in order to definitively proclaim his accession to the purple.
- ^4 When Septimius Severus accepted his rival, Albinus, as his associate on the
- imperial throne, he coined money at Rome in the name of Albinus as evidence to
- the latter of his agreement and good faith. ^5 Vopiscus, in his life of
- Firmus, asserts that the latter was no brigand, but a lawful sovereign, in
- whose name money had been coined. Pollion says that when Trebellius was
- elected emperor by the inhabitants of Isaurus, he immediately hastened to
- strike money as the sign of his accession to power. ^6 When the partisans of
- Procopius, the rival of Valens, sought to win Illyria to their master's cause,
- they exhibited the gold aurei which bore his name and effigy, as evidence that
- he was the rightful head of the Roman Empire. ^1 Moses of Khorene informs us
- that "when a new king of Persia ascended the throne, all the money in the
- royal treasury was recoined with his effigy." ^2 Even when countermarks were
- stamped upon the Roman coins, care was taken never to deface the effigy of the
- sacred emperor. ^3 The interchange of religious antipathy and defiance, which
- Abd-el-Melik and Justinian stamped upon their coins, is related elsewhere.
- Indeed, history is full of such instances. The coinage of money, and
- especially of gold, was always the prerogative of supreme authority. ^4 The
- jealous monopoly of gold coinage by the sovereign-pontiff ascends to the
- Achimenides of Persia, that is to say, to Cyrus and Darius; ^5 in fact, it
- ascends to the Bramins of India. The Greek and Roman Republics broke it down;
- Caesar set it up again.
-
- [Footnote 1: Herodian, i., 9.]
-
- [Footnote 2: "Dion. Cass.," lxxix., 4.]
-
- [Footnote 3: "Tact. Hist.," ii., 82.]
-
- [Footnote 4: Lampridinus, in "Diadumenus," 2.]
-
- [Footnote 5: Herodian, ii, 15.]
-
- [Footnote 6: "Thirty Tyrants," xxv.]
-
- [Footnote 1: "Ammianus Marcellinus," xxvi., 7.]
-
- [Footnote 2: Lavoix, Ms., p. 12.]
-
- [Footnote 3: Lenormant, ii., 389; iii., 389.]
-
- [Footnote 4: Lavoix, Ms., p. 16.]
-
- [Footnote 5: Lenormant, ii., 195, 196.]
-
- Assuming the common belief that the Christian princes of mediaeval Europe
- were in all respects independent sovereigns before the destruction of the
- Roman Empire by the fall of Constantinople, in 1204, it is difficult to
- explain the circumstance that none of them ever struck a gold coin before that
- event, and that all of them struck gold coins immediately afterwards. There
- was no abstention from gold coinage by either the Goths, the Celts, the
- Greeks, or the Romans-of-the-Commonwealth; there was no abstention from gold
- coinage by the Merovingian Franks or the Arabians of later ages; there was no
- lack of gold mines or of gold river-washings in any of the provinces or
- countries of the West; there was no want of knowledge concerning the manner of
- raising, smelting or stamping gold; yet we find the strange fact that wherever
- the authority of the Roman sovereign-pontiff was established, there and then
- the coinage, nay, sometimes even the production, of gold at once stopped. It
- must be borne in mind that it is not the use of gold coins to which reference
- is made, but the coinage - the minting and stamping of gold. In England gold
- coins, except during the early days of the Heptarchy, have been in use from
- the remotest era to the present time. Such coins were either Gothic
- (including Saxon), Celtic, Frankish or Moslem, but never Roman, unless struck
- by or under the sovereign-pontiff. In a word, for more than thirteen
- centuries - that is, from Augustus to Alexis IV. - the gold coins of the
- Empire, East and West, were struck exclusively by the Basileus. Again, from
- the eighth to the thirteenth century, a period of five hundred years, we have
- no evidence of any native Christian gold coinage under any of the kings of
- Britain. With the exception of a unique and dubious coin, now in the Paris
- collection, which bears the effigy of Louis le Debonnaire, the same is true of
- France, Germany, Italy; indeed, of all the provinces of the Empire whose
- princes were Christians.
-
- Before pointing out the significance of these circumstances, it will be
- useful to clear the ground by examining the explanations of others. Camden
- conjectures that "ignorance" was the cause; but Dr. Ruding very justly remarks
- that it could not have been ignorance of refining or coining gold, because
- silver, a much more difficult metal to treat, and one that in its natural
- state is nearly always combined with gold, had been refined and coined in
- Britain for many ages. ^1 Dr. Ruding and Lord Liverpool both have supposed
- that coins of gold were not wanted during the middle ages; but this is worse
- than Camden's conjecture, for it flies in the face of a palpable fact. That
- gold coins were indeed wanted is proved by the very common use of gold aurei,
- solidi, folles, or besants throughout all this period. Not only this, but the
- Arabian gold dinar, or mancus, was current in all the countries of the North;
- and either this coin or the gold maravedi was the principal medium of exchange
- in the trade of the Baltic.
-
- [Footnote 1: Camden's "Remains," art. "Money," p. 241.]
-
- Another explanation which has been advanced is, that the confusion caused
- by the conquests or revolts of the barbarians resulted in the closure of the
- gold mines, and rendered gold metal too scarce for coinage into money.
- Explanations which take no heed of the truth, made either in ignorance or
- desperation, may be multiplied indefinitely without serving any useful end.
- The facts were precisely the reverse of what is here assumed. It was the
- barbarians who opened the gold mines and the Christians who closed them. The
- heretical Moslem, Franks, Avars, Saxons, Norsemen and English all opened gold
- mines during the mediaeval ages. The moment these people became Christians,
- or were conquered or brought under the control of the Roman hierarchy, their
- gold mines began to be abandoned and closed. ^1
-
- [Footnote 1: "History Precious Metals;" "History Money."]
-
- All such futile explanations are effectually answered by the common use
- of Byzantine gold coins throughout Christendom. In England, for example, the
- exchequer rolls relating to the mediaeval ages, collated by Madox, prove that
- payments in gold besants were made every day, and that gold coins, as compared
- with silver ones, were as common then as now. ^2 If metal had been wanted for
- making English gold coins, it was to be had in sufficiency and at once. All
- that was necessary was to throw the besants into the English melting-pot. As
- for the feeble suggestion that for five hundred years no Christian princes
- wished to coin gold so long as the Basileus was willing to coin for them, when
- the coinage of gold was the universally recognized mark of sovereignty, and
- when, also, the profit, as we shall presently see, was one hundred per cent,
- it is scarcely worth answering. The greatest historians of the mediaeval ages
- - Montesquieu, Gibbon, Robertson, Hallam, Guizot, etc. - have neither remarked
- these facts nor sought for any explanation concerning the gold coinage. In
- their days the science of numismatics had not yet freed itself from the toils
- of the sophist and forger, and it offered but little aid to historical
- investigations. It has since become their chief reliance.
-
- [Footnote 2: Lord Liverpool does not appear to have perused this valuable and
- instructive work. For other historical omissions in his Letter to the King,
- see Sir David Balfour's Memorandum of October 20, 1887.]
-
- The true reason why gold money was always used but never coined by the
- princes of the mediaeval empire, relates not to any circumstances connected
- with the production, plentifulness, scarcity or metallurgical treatment of
- gold, but to that hierarchical constitution of pagan Rome, which afterwards
- with modifications became the constitution of Christian Rome. Under this
- constitution, and from the epoch of Julius to that of Alexis, the mining and
- coinage of gold was a prerogative attached to the office of the
- sovereign-pontiff, and was, therefore, an article of the Roman constitution
- and of the Roman religion. Although it is probable that during the dark and
- middle ages the prerogative of mining was violated by many who would never
- have dared to commit the more easily detected sacrilege of coinage, there are
- no evidences of such violation by Christians.
-
- The mines of Kremnitz, which contained both silver and gold, and which
- Agricola says were opened in A. D. 550, were in the territory of the pagan
- Avars; the gold washings of the Elbe, re-opened in 719, were in the hands of
- the pagan Saxons and Merovingian Franks; so were the gold washings of the
- Rhine, Rhone and Garonne; the gold mines of Africa and Spain, re-opened in the
- eighth century, were worked by the heretical Moslem; the gold mines of
- Kaurzim, in Bohemia, opened in 998, were managed by pagan Czechs. Whenever
- and wherever Christianity was established, gold mining appears to have been
- relinquished to the Basileus or abandoned altogether. So long as the
- Byzantine empire lasted, neither the emperor of the West, nor any of the other
- princes of Christendom, except the Basileus himself, seem to have conducted or
- permitted gold mining.
-
- With regard to gold coinage the facts are simple and indisputable. Julius
- Caesar erected the coinage of gold into a sacerdotal prerogative; this
- prerogative was attached to the sovereign and his successors, not as the
- emperors, but as the high priests of Rome; it was enjoyed by every Basileus,
- whether pagan or Christian, of the joint and Eastern empires from the Julian
- conquest of Alexandria to the papal destruction of Constantinople; the pieces
- bore the rayed effigies of the deified Caesars, and some of them the legend
- "Theos Sebastos." When emperor-worship was succeeded by Christianity they bore
- the effigy of Jesus Christ. ^1 It would have been sacrilege, punishable by
- torture, death and anathema for any other prince than the sovereign-pontiff to
- strike coins of gold; it would have been sacrilege to give currency to any
- others; hence no other Christian prince, not even the pope of Rome, nor the
- sovereign of the Western or Mediaeval "empire," attempted to coin gold while
- the ancient Empire survived.
-
- [Footnote 1: William Till (p. 39) says that Justin II. (A. D. 565-78) first
- struck the aureus (solidus, or besant) with the effigy of Christ and the
- legend "Dominus Noster, Jesus Christus, rex regnantium," and that this
- practice was observed down to the fall of the Byzantine empire. This
- statement is erroneous in several respects. The first name of Christ on the
- Roman coins was never spelled "Jesus," but, successively, "Ihs," "Issus," and
- "Iesus." The effigy of Christ did not appear on the coins of Justin II. It
- first appeared on a gold solidus of Justinian II. (Rhinotmetus), who reigned
- 685-95, and again 705-11 (Sabatier, "Monnaies Byzantines," ii., 22).]
-
- Says Procopius: "Every liberty was given by the Basileus Justinian I. to
- subordinate princes to coin silver as much as they chose, but they must not
- strike gold coins, no matter how much gold they possessed;" and he intimates
- that the distinction was neither new nor its significance doubtful. Theophanus
- (eighth century), Cedrenus (eleventh century), and Zonaras (twelfth century)
- state that Justinian II. broke the peace of 686 with Abd-el-Melik because the
- latter paid his tribute in pieces of gold which bore not the effigy of the
- Roman emperor. In vain the Arabian caliph pleaded that the coins were of full
- weight and fineness, and that the Arabian merchants would not accept coins of
- the Roman type. Here are the exact words of Zonaras: "Justinian broke the
- treaty with the Arabs because the annual tribute was paid, not in pieces with
- the imperial effigy, but after a new type, and it is not permitted to stamp
- gold coins with any other effigy but that of the emperor of Rome." ^1 The "new
- type" complained of probably had as much to do with the matter as the absence
- of Justinian's effigy. That new type was the effigy of Abd-el-Melik with a
- drawn sword in his hand, and the Mahometan religious formula: a triple offense
- - an insult, a defiance and a sacrilege.
-
- [Footnote 1: From the period A. D. 645, when their conquests deprived the
- Roman empire of the bulk of its Asiatic and African possessions, to about the
- beginning of the eighth century. the Arabians struck coins with the effigy of
- the Roman emperor and the emblems P* and the cross. At that period they
- struck coins still with these emblems, but in place of the emperor's effigy,
- that of Abd-el-Melik with a drawn sword in hand. Like the maravedis of Henry
- III. (1257) and the nobles of Edward III. (1344), the issue of these coins
- amounted to an assertion of independent sovereignty, and as such was resented
- by Justinian. To the nummulary proclamation of the Arabian: "The servant of
- God, Abd-el-Melik, Emir-el-Moumenin," the Roman replied: "Our Lord Justinian,
- servant of Christ."]
-
- The privilege accorded to subject-kings with regard to silver was
- extended to both mining and coinage. Silver mining and coinage was conducted
- by all the Western princes, the Western emperor included. The pope disposed
- of a few coining privileges to new or weak States, or dependent bishoprics,
- the Western emperor disposed of others to the commercial cities; but for the
- most part silver was coined by the feudal princes, each for himself, and not
- under any continuing prerogative of the empire, whether ancient or mediaeval.
-
- The following table shows some of the earliest gold coinages of Christian
- Europe: -
-
-
- [See Table 27: Gold Coinages.]
-
- That Christian Europe abstained from coining gold for five centuries
- because such coinage was a prerogative of the Basileus, is an explanation that
- may not be acceptable to the old school of historians; but this is not a
- sufficient reason for its rejection. The old school would have been very
- greedy of knowledge if they had not left something for the new school to
- discover.
-
- In his "Science des Medailles" (i., 208-11), Father Joubert, and after
- him other numismatists, observing the strange abstention of the Christian
- princes from coining gold, and perhaps anxious to supply a reason for it which
- would have the effect to discourage any further examination of so suggestive a
- topic, invented or promulgated the ingenious doctrine that the Roman emperors
- from the time of Augustus were invested, in like manner, with the power to
- coin both gold and silver. If this doctrine enjoyed the advantage of being
- sound, it would deprive the long abstention from gold coinage by the Western
- princes of much of its significance; because, assuming that the coinage of
- gold and silver stood upon the same footing, and remembering that all the
- Christian princes coined silver, their omission to coin gold might, with some
- reason, be attributed to indifference. But that Father Joubert's doctrine is
- not sound is easily proved.
-
- I. With the accession of Julius Caesar was enacted a new and memorable
- change in the monetary system of Rome. The gold aureus was made the sole
- unlimited universal legal-tender coin of the empire; the silver and copper
- coins were limited and localized in legal tender; the ratio of gold to silver
- in the coinage was suddenly - and in the face of greatly increased supplies
- of gold bullion - raised from 9 silver to 12 silver for 1 gold; and the
- mining and commerce of gold were seized, controlled, and strictly monopolized
- by the sovereign-pontiff; whereas the mining of silver was thrown open to
- subsidiary princes and certain privileged individuals. ^1 With the production
- of gold thus limited to pontifical control, and that of silver thrown open
- to numerous persons, the coinage of the two metals in like manner, or under
- like conditions, was totally impracticable and historically untrue. ^1
-
- [Footnote 1: The exportation of gold had been previously controlled by the
- Senate. Caesar made it a prerogative of the sovereign-pontiff.]
-
- [Footnote 1: See "History Money," chapter xxv., for further consideration of
- this subject.]
-
- II. As will presently be shown more at length, the imperial treasury -
- which was kept distinct from the public treasury, and known by another name -
- was organized as a sacred institution; its chief officer, then or later on,
- was invested with a sacred title; the coinage of gold, which was placed under
- its management, was exercised as a sacred prerogative; and the coins
- themselves were stamped with sacred emblems and legends. ^2 On the contrary,
- the coinage of silver was a secular prerogative; it belonged to the emperor as
- a secular monarch, and as such it was thrown open to the subsidiary princes,
- nobles and cities of the empire, while that of copper-bronze was resigned to
- the Senate. These are not like conditions of coinage, but, on the contrary,
- very unlike ones.
-
- [Footnote 2: The officers of the sacred fisc, who were stationed in the
- provinces to superintend the collection of gold for the sacred mint at
- Constantinople, are mentioned in the Notitia Imperii.]
-
- III. From the accession of Julius to the fall of Constantinople, the
- ratio of value between gold and silver within the Roman empire, whether pagan
- or Christian, was always 1 to 12; whereas, during the same interval, it was 1
- to 6 1/2 in India, as well as in the Arabian empires, in Asia, Africa and
- Spain; and it was 1 to 8 in Freisland, Scandinavia, and the Baltic provinces.
- It is inconceivable that one single unvarying ratio of 1 to 12 should have
- been maintained for centuries by the innumerable and irreconcilable feudal
- provinces of the Roman empire, if the freedom to coin silver, exercised by the
- feudal princes, was in like manner extended to gold.
-
- IV. The authority of ancient writers is conclusive on this subject.
- Cicero, Pliny, Procopius, and Zonaras, though they lived in distant ages, all
- concur in representing that the coinage of the two precious metals was not
- conducted in like manner nor under like conditions.
-
- V. The authority of modern writers, for example, Letronne, Mommsen, and
- Lenormant, is to the same effect. This absolutely closes the subject, and
- completely disposes of Father Joubert.
-
- The sacerdotal character conferred upon gold, or the coinage of gold, was
- not a novelty of the Julian constitution; rather was it an ancient myth put to
- new political use. Concerning the testimony of witnesses, the very ancient
- Hindu Code says: "By speaking falsely in a cause concerning gold, he kills the
- born and the unborn" - an extreme anathema. Stealing sacred gold is classed
- with the highest crimes. ^1 A similar solicitude and veneration for gold
- occurs elsewhere throughout these laws. The Buddhists made it unlawful to
- mine for, or even to handle gold, probably because the Bramins had used it as
- an engine of tyranny. According to Mr. Ball, this superstition is still
- observed in some remote parts of India. It is possible that, in some
- instances, the sacerdotal character attached to gold by the Bramins belonged
- only to such of it as had been paid to the priests, or consecrated to the
- temples, and that when the priests paid it away it was no longer sacred; but
- the texts will not always bear this reading. For example: "He who steals a
- suvarna" (suvarna, a gold coin) "dies on a dunghill, is turned to a serpent,
- and rots in hell until the dissolution of the universe," (vide Braminical
- inscription found on copperplate dug up at Raiwan, in Delhi). ^2 The same
- superstition occurs among the ancient Egyptians, Persians and Jews. There are
- frequent allusions to it in the pages of Herodotus. For example, Targitaus,
- the first king of Scythia, a thousand years before Darius, the sacred king of
- Persia (this would make it about B. C. 1500), was the divine son of Jupiter
- and a daughter of the river Borysthenes or Dneister. In the kingdom of
- Targitaus gold was found in abundance, but being deemed sacred, it was
- reserved for the use of the sacred king. In another place Herodotus relates
- that in the reign of Darius, B. C. 521 (of whom Lenormant says, in his great
- work on the "Moneys of Antiquity," that he reserved the coinage of gold to
- himself absolutely), Aryandes, his viceroy in Egypt, struck a silver coin to
- resemble the gold darics of the king. Possibly, to make the resemblance
- greater, it was also gilded. For this offense Aryandes was condemned as a
- traitor and executed. ^1 Josephus makes many allusions to the sacredness of
- gold. A similar belief is to be noticed among the ancient Greeks, whose
- coinages, except during the republican era, were conducted in the temples and
- under the supervision of priests. Upon these issues were stamped the
- symbolism and religion of the State, and as only the priesthood could
- correctly illustrate these mysteries of their own creation, the coinage - at
- least that of the more precious pieces - naturally became a prerogative of
- their order. Rawlinson notices that the Parthian kings, even after they threw
- off the Syro-Macedonian yoke, never ventured to strike gold coins. ^2 The
- reason probably was that in place of the Syro-Macedonian yoke they had
- accepted the Roman, and that the Roman (imperial) law forbade the coinage of
- gold to subject-princes.
-
- [Footnote 1: Halhed's "Gentoo Code," viii., 99; ix., 237.]
-
- [Footnote 2: "Jour. Asiat. Soc. Bengal," lvi., 118.]
-
- [Footnote 1: Mel., 7, 166; Lenormant, i., 173.]
-
- [Footnote 2: Geo. Rawlinson, "Seventh Monarchy," p 70.]
-
- Whatever credit or significance be accorded or denied to these ancient
- glimpses of the myth, its significance becomes clearer when it is viewed
- through the accounts of the Roman historians. The Sacred Myth of Gold appears
- in Rome at the period when the history of the Gaulish invasion of A. U. 369
- was written. The story runs that after the eternal city had been saved from
- the barbarians, it was held by the Roman leaders that to the gold which had
- been taken from the mass belonging to the temples should be added the gold
- contributed by the women towards making up the ransom, or indemnity, of a
- thousand pounds weight, and that all of it should thenceforth be regarded as
- sacred. Says Livy: "The gold which had been rescued from payment to the
- Gauls, as also what had been, during the hurry of the alarm, carried from the
- other temples into the recess of Jupiter's temple, was altogether judged to be
- sacred, and ordered to be deposited together under the throne of Jupiter." ^1
-
- [Footnote 1: Livy, v., 50.]
-
-